Introduction to Demand and Supply

image
Figure 2.1 Farmer’s Market Organic vegetables and fruits that are grown and sold within a specific geographical region should, in theory, cost less than conventional produce because the transportation costs are less. That is not, however, usually the case. (Credit: Modification of Farmer’s Market by Natalie Maynor / Flickr CC BY 2.0)

BRING IT HOME

Why Can We Not Get Enough of Organic?

Organic food is increasingly popular, not just in the United States but worldwide. At one time, consumers had to go to specialty stores or farmers’ markets to find organic produce. Now it is available in most grocery stores. In short, organic is part of the mainstream.

Ever wondered why organic food costs more than conventional food? Why, say, does an organic Fuji apple cost $1.99 a pound, while its conventional counterpart costs $1.49 a pound? The same price relationship is true for just about every organic product on the market. If many organic foods are locally grown, would they not take less time to get to market and therefore be cheaper? What are the forces that keep those prices from coming down? Turns out those forces have quite a bit to do with this chapter’s topic: demand and supply.

Chapter Overview

In this chapter, you will learn about:

  • Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium in Markets for Goods and Services
  • Shifts in Demand and Supply for Goods and Services
  • Changes in Equilibrium Price

An auction bidder pays thousands of dollars for a dress Whitney Houston wore. A collector spends a small fortune for a few drawings by John Lennon. People usually react to purchases like these in two ways: either their jaw drops because they think these are high prices to pay for such goods, or they think these are rare, desirable items, and the amount paid seems right.

LINK IT UP

Huffpost’s 2012 list of bizarre items that have been purchased for their ties to celebrities offers an insight into an interesting aspect of demand and supply.

When economists talk about prices, they are less interested in making judgments than in gaining a practical understanding of what determines prices and why prices change. Consider a price most of us contend with weekly: that of a gallon of gas. Why was the average price of gasoline in the United States $3.71 per gallon in June 2014? Why did the price of gasoline fall sharply to $1.96 per gallon by January 2016? To explain these price movements, economists focus on the determinants of what gasoline buyers are willing to pay and what gasoline sellers are willing to accept.

As it turns out, the price of gasoline in June of any given year is nearly always higher than the price in January of that same year. Over recent decades, gasoline prices in midsummer have averaged about 10 cents per gallon more than their midwinter low. The likely reason is that people drive more in the summer, and are also willing to pay more for gas, but that does not explain why gas prices fell so steeply. Other factors were at work during those 18 months, such as increases in supply and decreases in the demand for crude oil.

This chapter introduces the economic model of demand and supply—one of the most powerful models in all of economics. The discussion here begins by examining how demand and supply determine the price and the quantity sold in markets for goods and services, and how changes in demand and supply lead to changes in prices and quantities.

License

Icon for the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License

UH Microeconomics 2019 Copyright © by Terianne Brown; Cynthia Foreman; Thomas Scheiding; and Openstax is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, except where otherwise noted.

Share This Book